Licence to be Bad by Jonathan Aldred [Book Summary – Review]


What exactly is entrepreneurship? Does it fall under the category of science? A course in human sciences? Is it about sentiment or reality?

In past years, many academics have referred to finance as a “scientific discipline,” much like engineering or chemistry. This indicates that it specializes in impersonal facts and exact figures. However, this is untrue. Contrary to what academics would wish us to assume, finance is not scientific.

Within those sections, we will dissect a few financial theories and rules and demonstrate just how frail and unreliable they are. You will discover how numerous of the “facts” that support humanity are also not entirely correct in the procedure.

The following sections will teach you

  • why it is ineffective to bribe bosses;
  • why it is not difficult to have freedom; and
  • what a snowfall has in common with the financial sector.

Buy this book from Amazon


Chapter 1 – Our style of reasoning has mostly been influenced by a divisive set of unrestricted economic theories.


Let’s go back in time to 1948.

Europe’s industries are in ruins one year after the conclusion of the Second World War. A program of greater state expenditure is currently in place as part of a worldwide attempt to spur the economy. Keynesian Economics, a renowned analyst, is driving this approach. Keynesian is certain that public expenditure programs are the sole option to restart Europe’s businesses.

Heinrich Hertz and a tiny, rebellious band of economists, however, are in disagreement. On Monte Pèlerin, a mountainous area of the Swiss Alps, Hertz arranges a meeting of this association. Even though Hertz’s supporters constituted the minority in 1948, it would not take much time to allow them to gain dominance.

A few of the Monte Pèlerin participants later helped found the Chicagoland College of Economics. The fundamental tenet of Chicagoland College is that regulators and authorities must minimize their involvement in the economy. Where cash is earned and spent must be decided by the market economy, not by elected representatives.

The university gave Neoliberal economics and Neoconservatism, which brought revolutionary free-market philosophy to the United States and the United Kingdom, correspondingly, in the 1980s, their theoretical foundation. It has subsequently dominated, in addition to other philosophically comparable notions, and many people consider it to be the only legitimate approach to thinking regarding economic principles. Yet are they accurate?

Let’s examine a few instances to understand how such financial reasoning functions in actual life.

The world’s economy collapsed in 2008. Numerous individuals sacrificed their employment and way of life as a result of the collapse of the economy and institutions. Nevertheless, who was at fault? Instead of blaming the institutions directly, many individuals have blamed the regulatory agencies, referring to states and parliamentarians.

That would be like accusing the authorities of a robbery, which is absurd. Why does it, therefore, make sense in terms of finances? Indeed, Chicagoland College promotes reasoning like this.

Theoretical perspective also informs our understanding of the environment. Nowadays, it is indeed easy to acquire the unrestricted mentality, which holds that since our contributions to progress are so negligible, they are not even worthwhile. Mancur Olsen, an American analyst, gave this gloomy point of view economic credibility in the mid-1960s. And it is already causing our earth’s natural destruction.

The absolute reality is very different from freedom of thought and Chicagoland College reasoning. However, this is a common way of thinking about the social and economic environment. You will learn why such reasoning falls flat in the following sections.


Chapter 2 – Game theory promotes an unusually self-centered worldview.


Most likely, you have known of game theory. This renowned method of analysis makes behavior predictions based on people’s reasonable choices. John g. Friedmann, a statistician, popularized game theory in the decades following the Second World War by advising the United States administration to attack the Soviets as quickly as possible. President Reagan, fortunately, disapproved.

Howard Kenny, another American, advanced game theory by highlighting the importance of self-interest. He thought that everyone behaved selfishly. If someone appeared to be collaborating, this was only since it was to their individual greatest advantage at the time.

However, are individuals genuinely always selfless? One thing is for certain: You are more inclined to behave cruelly yourself if you believe that everyone else is being cruel.

The Prisoner’s Dilemma is the best-recognized illustration of game theory. Imagine being held in different cells by your guilty partner. The police believe you and a serious criminal have worked together. So they propose a compromise: admit and bring your spouse in, and you will get away with it while they’ll serve decades.

However, they provide your spouse with the same bargain. So you will both receive 8 years if you each confess. When neither of you admits, you will each receive two.

What then do you do? Confession is the traditional game-theory response. Consider this: if your partner admits, it is healthier if you do too, resulting in 8 rather than a decade in prison. This is still preferable if you disclose even if your spouse does not. Yes, your spouse is jailed for 5 to 10 years, yet you escape punishment.

There are numerous uses for The Prisoner’s Dilemma. Standing higher in the crowd will allow you to view greater portions of the activity, while others will catch fewer of it. In an ideal world, all of us would remain seated, however many do so simply because several people stand. Co2 emissions are another factor. The perfect situation would be for all countries to reduce their emissions, but moving first would benefit no state.

However, do we constantly have such self-centered thoughts? There is a ton of evidence to support the notion that individuals do work together to maximize the result. For instance, there has been a certain international collaboration over environmental impacts. Global peace agreements have also naturally stopped the nuclear war.

It is a positive idea that game theory does not anticipate how people will act. However, the simple fact that it exists supports a specific, icy selfish worldview.


Chapter 3 – By accident, Ronald Coase encouraged economics to elevate trade negotiations.


How can government agencies lower unemployment? One solution is to pay companies.

This occurred in Illinois in 1984. Nearly 5,000 jobless individuals were asked to participate in a study where their business would get $600 when they were able to secure and maintain employment.

The research didn’t go well at all. A third of those who were invited to participate declined, and much more than half of the businesses that were eligible to receive the incentive opted not to. Making that kind of transaction simply seemed wrong.

The Coase Theorem, a concept in economics, served as the basis for the Illinois system. However, even Coase, after whom it is called, disagreed with that as well.

Put two peasants in the picture. The second peasant’s crops are consumed by the first peasant’s cattle. Coase noted that the peasants would consider the expense of installing a border in comparison to the extent of harm, and they would just do so if it was less expensive.

Who of the peasants, though, is actually in the right legitimately? Contrary to conventional wisdom, Coase argued that the law should only be a separate concern. He contended that peasants are more focused on financial effectiveness than on judicial fairness.

The agricultural’ deal will still be impacted by the law, however. Because there are fees associated with transactions during the legal procedure. The ideal option for the agricultural producers may alter if you take into account all the costs and effort that the procedure can require, including the hours spent on research, legal expenses, and debate.

The main argument made by Coase was straightforward. Making decisions is impacted by trading costs. The Chicagoland college of economics, however, had a different perspective. For them, the tale served as an example of why management fees should indeed be kept to a minimum, i.e., with minimal intrusion from authorities or the legal system.

Economics has been moved in some strange places by this kind of reasoning. The unsuccessful Illinois business bribery plan was designed to promote straightforward wheeling and dealing on Coasean principles. Even the contentious Coasean analyst Richard Resnick advocated for a free market for infants rather than the foster system.

Emission prices have also been impacted by the Coase Theorem. Businesses and governments can place bids for the right to release a specific quantity of carbon dioxide and then sell those privileges. The system promotes short-term thinking and minimizes the true harm that contamination does.

Coase wanted to highlight how significant transactional expenses are. However, a misunderstanding of his ideas has caused current economists to attempt to downplay them. He did not intend that.


Chapter 4 – A variety of financial ideas wrongly criticizes the government.


Democracy is unattainable. A good one, huh? Through the efforts of analyst Kenneth Arrows, this catchphrase became quite well-known. But it is best contested.

A statistical theorem known as Arrow’s Improbability Theorem demonstrates that no form of consensus decision can end in a situation where everyone gets what they desire. That would imply, for instance, that no one could be elected in a real democratic manner.

However, a few of the conclusions drawn by Arrow’s theory may not always hold in reality. One of them is that all potential benefits must be ranked completely, from greatest to worst, by judgment algorithms. Many more of our contests just need one victor. Therefore, the result of Arrow does not at all applicable to them. Even so, the adage endures.

The public choice theory was created by American analysts James M. Wright in the mid-1970s. In simplest terms, the free market theory contends that all participants in democracy, including voters and government servants in addition to elected officials, are egocentric. Additionally, this greed is the cause of all that occurs in democracy, including a politician’s decision of policies.

According to public choice theory, there is an excessive amount of federal restriction and legislators are more driven by the need to win elections than by the goal of achieving good. Additionally, it paints the average voter as being uninformed, selfish, and foolishly preoccupied with immediate gain. These are currently accepted viewpoints.

Does the public choice theory hold up? It surely has a lot of inconsistencies. For example, even though it asserts that people are simple to trick, it also encouraged Ronald Reagan to campaign for the presidency on a platform of cutting back on government expenditure. His triumph is unequivocal evidence that individuals are occasionally prepared to set aside their immediate interests.

However, the self-fulfilling nature of a public choice theory cannot be ignored. Employees in the government sphere are significantly more inclined to behave badly themselves when they are informed that everybody else is. When voters and legislators believe that everybody else is acting selfishly, then they will begin to follow suit. This is another negative outcome of economic theory; it is a fulfillment rather than an inevitable outcome.


Chapter 5 – Though seductive, an unrestricted mentality can have terrible repercussions.


Here is one example. Two offenders are aiming their weapons at the target and are about to shoot. However, just one of those does so in reality. Who is the assassin? the shooter, am I correct?

If the first offender had not been discharged, the second would have. However, it does not lessen the perpetrator’s culpability; each judicial process would concur that the murderer was the perpetrator who shot the weapon. More broadly, simply because another person might act similarly doesn’t make it any less of a person’s obligation.

However, in other circumstances, we appear to believe that since we are a member of a community, our unfavorable inputs do not count. This is independent thinking, and it is also ruining the environment in which we live.

Free-rider allure has existed for thousands of years. It is scorned by Aristotle in Plato’s Republic. However, the 20th-century analyst Mancur Olsen revived the concept more subsequently.

Assume there is a storm and one individual is using a pail to attempt to stop it. Are they assisting? In no way. In reality, such labor serves no purpose and is not even commendable. Free riding, in Olsen’s opinion, is the sensible course of action. When you are not planning to alter anything, there is no use in attempting.

Today, an unrestricted mentality is pervasive. Consider tax avoidance. Since the late 1970s, we have grown accustomed to anticipating that businesses will use every tax-related opportunity at their disposal to minimize their tax obligations. When all of your rivals are attempting to avoid tax, it would not appear to be any value in having a substantial tax rate.

We have a disgracefully sluggish reaction to the threat posed by global warming because of this same kind of reasoning. People are eager to emphasize that the impact people can have is negligible in comparison to what large corporations and governments might do. People merely have more influence than what unrestricted theory implies.

Consequently, the contributions of several people can truly have an impact. A turning point can be reached by the bulk of individuals, spurring more extensive responses. So this is what we ought to aim for.

Independent thinking incorporates a strategy that is quite unhelpful in daily life. The fact is significantly less complicated. Community engagement can truly change things if we all work together. And we could all be made accountable when we do not work together.


Chapter 6 – The application of the theoretical framework to daily life could lead to certain unexpected outcomes.


The majority of the instances up to this point would not even be considered orthodox economists. And besides, topics like elections and the global warming crisis are also not entirely comparable to charts of producers and consumers.

However, there has been a shift toward a general macroeconomic view of the globe since the late 1970s. The main objective is to rely solely on effective, financially beneficial reasoning.

An American analyst by the name of Howard Becker served as its leader. Despite the protest’s continued influence, a few of Becker’s ideas concerning the application of economists remain somewhat startling.

In 1988, Becker put out the idea that border policies ought to be focused on financial stability. Everyone was angry at the time, but today this is a standard procedure. You could even purchase a membership in several nations by making a specified investment in property. The United States and other nations in Europe are included as well.

Becker proposed that the United States judicial process might save funds by lengthening terms in the late 1970s and early 1980s. He claimed that harsher punishments will deter future offenders from engaging in crimes and reduce the need for enforced expenditures. This was a complete failure; in reality, violence increased with reduced police personnel patrolling the streets. The truth is that Becker’s precise market theory was not how offenders decided what to do.

Becker’s theories were built on the premise that individuals frequently make logical choices. He claimed that occasionally people have unexpected preferences as an explanation for choices that appear to be unreasonable. For example, those who smoke were choosing to live shorter lives on purpose. They preferred to lead a shorter life while continuing to smoke versus longer lives while quitting.

Becker also attempted to rationalize and explain conventional family structures in terms of economics. Considering that both people can focus on the chores that fitted them easiest, he claimed that the conventional group of working men and women constituted the most effective method of living.

To see the rest of the universe in Becker’s words is not only out of date but also bizarre. Nevertheless, this style of reasoning is still prevalent. Becker is prominently referenced in the hugely successful publication Trade – theory, which adapts logical arguments to a variety of vivid situations. The issue is that viewing life through the icy, too analytical lenses of economic man are almost a beneficial approach to living.


Chapter 7 – Rewards are not always used by individuals in the manner that analysts anticipate.


Many daycare facilities in Aviv, Israeli, have an issue with families picking up their kids late in the nineties. Therefore they began levying fines. Additionally, there were many late catches.

This is another illustration. The UK government began charging for every bag in 2010 to reduce the consumption of solitary plastic containers. This was essentially a modest charge. Consumption decreased by 70%.

Why are the outcomes so distinct? Simply said, communication In actuality, rewards and sanctions only function when they successfully compel the target audience. In the conclusion, it goes beyond financial considerations.

A significant public outreach effort explaining the rationale behind the UK’s introduction of the packaging waste tax had also been announced at the same time. However, the families in the Aviv daycare facilities have not explained the text. Conversely, they perceived the penalty as a cost they might choose to incur, which made them feel less bad about being late.

In his 1969 article The Present Partnership, British scholar Eric Titmuss provides another excellent illustration of a failing reward. He looks at the US asserts that explored compensating individuals to contribute blood instead of simply requiring them to do so.

In the end, the study was a complete failure. Many donations of blood were of poor quality because certain donors lied about their health information due to the cash reward. In addition, several individuals who might have contributed were turned off by the reward. Cash was not important to them. They stopped being interested when they stopped believing that donating blood was a charitable gesture. The lesson? Humans are complicated beings, and they don’t all have financial motivations.

According to many economists, each person has a cost. Even if such were the case, a plethora of moral considerations would still be raised. To begin with, there are situations when rewarding somebody is plain unethical, such as when paying a court.

Additionally, individuals are capable of performing activities they would never typically consider when under immense stress. They might experience this if they are given an absurdly large amount of cash or, on the opposite side if they are blackmailed with punishment. Instead of being motivated, individuals are becoming perverted in these situations. “The simple presence of options is indeed not… adequate to constitute my conduct free,” said British philosopher Isaac Berliner.


Chapter 8 – We have severe flaws in our probabilities estimation methods.


For Daniel Viniar, who was Barclays’ CFO at the time, July 2008 was a nerve-wracking month. He refers to price fluctuations as “20-standard deviation shifts” that occur “many days straight” in a discussion with the Economic Times.

Below than once throughout the cosmos, a 20-standard deviation change is equivalent to receiving the British lotto 15 times at a time. However, throughout the collapse, similar occurrences occurred often rather than simply once. There are still two options. Either the analysis technique was flawed, or we were all simply extremely unfortunate.

The issue is, such improbable things have occurred before in the financial sector. Just think back to Black Friday in 1988 and the dot-com boom in the 1990s. It’s quite obvious that the analysis is flawed.

The normality test, which has the bell-shaped curve you have encountered in numerous academic books, is the framework that is most frequently used while computing chances. Occurrences such as the economic meltdown are positioned near the curve’s extremes, far enough away to be insignificant.

Yet not all data is distributed normally. The trend is distinct, for example, when you examine the market for stocks. It possesses a cyclic pattern, a type of feature that also governs the size of disasters and the shape of snowflakes. Harmonic distributes are magnitude, meaning you could move into or out and still observe the same shapes.

In contrast to a bell curve, the probability falls much more progressively below a nonlinear distribution. Even though events such as the economic meltdown are still extremely unusual, it is not so uncommon that we ought to ignore them completely. The issue is that this procedure needs a large amount of information to assess probability, and especially in the situation of economic disasters, we lack sufficient amounts of that.

This only points to a more general fact about the possibility: some aspects are unclear. Especially if we are merely speculating, it is far too usual to give chances to all. One more urgent instance is global warming. The predictions of the harm it will do are hazy, general, and predicated on dubious premises. Several systems use the erroneous assumption that the existence of upcoming generations becomes less valuable than our own.

We could benefit significantly if we were open about the boundaries of possibility and acknowledged that there are some issues we have no idea about.


Chapter 9 – Excessive disparity is unintentionally tolerated by mainstream capitalism.


The current state of the globe’s disparity is widely acknowledged. Strangely enough, though, there is approximately the same disparity among the wealthy as it would be in general.

The dispersion of inequity is cyclic, similar to the share prices and snowfall in the section before. As a result, it is magnitude. Let’s suppose you examine the revenue of the entire country and discover that the wealthiest 2% receives about 25% of total revenue. Because of magnitude, you can move in and observe that the highest 2% of earners make up the wealthiest 2% and account for 25% of total revenue.

Therefore, is extreme inequity unavoidable? They are not. In nations like the United States and the United Kingdom that have implemented trade reforms supporting private enterprise since the early 1990s, inequity has only increased. Nothing similar has occurred elsewhere. It is possible to lessen inequity.

Many individuals think that you receive whatever you earn. Consider the stereotypes we perpetuate towards the wealthy. Would a person with Bill Gates’ level of extraordinary riches truly deserve it? Gates hailed from a wealthy family, and his discoveries drew on previous research. His economic achievement, however, dwarfs that of many others.

We do not just accept this injustice, but we actively promote it. America’s highest marginal rates of taxation are a good demonstration of the above. Although the highest rate of taxation under President Truman was 89 percent, it is generally agreed upon that heavy taxation deter business growth.

However, that presumption is gravely incorrect. Now consider it: if your taxation became reduced, would you feel encouraged to put in more effort? But if nothing, a reduction in taxes will probably put you further at ease because you will be getting paid greater for performing the same quantity of labor. Additionally, keep in mind that taxes are beneficial and generate the funding required for essential public services. We should not always be trying to get a better deal.

A further illustration of the faulty logic that underlies many contemporary theoretical approaches is the notion that individuals are driven by cutting taxes. As we have discovered in all these sections, moral judgments—often disguised as factual statements frequently made, and they’re risky decisions at that.

Theoretical approaches don’t always accurately portray how people behave; thus, we must cease assuming what they were doing. The moment has come to stop listening to economics and to take comfort in knowing that no one else is an economic man.


Licence to be Bad: How Economics Corrupted Us by Jonathan Aldred Book Review


A broad range of economic theories that frequently promote the capitalist model has recently gained significant sway over how we formulate policy and the way we behave. A blatantly self-centered perspective on the globe has come to be accepted as the mainstream thanks to concepts including behavioral economics, societal behavioral economics, and freedom of thought. It is time to stop listening to such analysts who attempt to pass off their unfavorable views as facts.


Buy this book from Amazon



Download Pdf


https://goodbooksummary.s3.us-east-2.amazonaws.com/Licence+to+be+Bad+by+Jonathan+Aldred+Book+Summary+-+Review.pdf


Download Epub


https://goodbooksummary.s3.us-east-2.amazonaws.com/Licence+to+be+Bad+by+Jonathan+Aldred+Book+Summary+-+Review.epub


Audiobook


Savaş Ateş

I'm a software engineer. I like reading books and writing summaries. I like to play soccer too :) Good Reads Profile: https://www.goodreads.com/user/show/106467014-sava-ate

Recent Posts